Keynesian principles are so widely employed by governments that other perspectives are often eschewed by economic theorists attempting to control inflation, employment, and balances of trade. One must note that Keynesian thought is rooted, first and foremost, in Historicism. The Historical School of Economics is a school of economic thought that flourished in the 19th century. This school of economics sought to understand the economic history of nations in order to gain insight into present and future economic trends. It looked at the historical development of economic activities and institutions, and the social and cultural factors that influenced these developments. In particular, the Historical School was concerned with understanding how different nations had developed differently, and how this could be used to inform economic policies. The Historical School of Economics was made up of several prominent economists, such as Gustav von Schmoller, Wilhelm Roscher and Karl Knies, who argued that economic analysis should be based on historical evidence, not abstract theories. They argued for considering a variety of factors, including social and cultural values, when making economic decisions. This school of thought was influential in its time, and it laid the foundations for the development of economics as a social science. However, its influence has declined in recent years, as more modern approaches to economics have become more popular. Nevertheless, the Historical School of Economics still has a role to play in informing economic policies and understanding the economic history of nations.
Marxian Economics is an important economic theory developed by Karl Marx, who is a renowned philosopher and economist. It is a branch of economic thought and analysis that focuses on the study of capitalism and its effects on society. The main premise of Marxian Economics is that capitalism would eventually lead to the exploitation of labor and the accumulation of wealth by a small number of individuals. Marx argued that the only way to achieve economic equality was to overthrow the capitalist system and replace it with a socialist one. This would lead to a more equitable distribution of wealth and a better quality of life for everyone. He believed that the only way to achieve this was through a revolution, and he advocated for a revolutionary approach to economics. Marxian Economics has been used to analyze and explain the economic systems and trends in the world today. It has been used to examine the effects of different economic policies and to form arguments for economic reform. It is an important theory that provides a deeper understanding of the world economy and how it works. Neoclassical Economics is a school of economic thought that emerged in the late 19th and early 20th centuries. Neoclassical Economists, like Alfred Marshall, John Maynard Keynes and Vilfredo Pareto, developed theories that assumed that people were rational economic actors who made decisions based on maximizing their own benefits. The theory relied on the use of mathematical models to analyze economic behavior and the interactions between supply and demand. It is still used extensively today and has been adapted and modified over time to account for new economic realities. Neoclassical Economics has been criticized as unrealistic and overly simplistic, as it fails to consider the complexities of the real world. However, it remains an important and influential school of thought and continues to be used by economists and policymakers around the world.
The Austrian School of Economics is a school of economic thought founded in the late 19th century in Vienna, Austria. It draws its inspiration from Adam Smith’s work and is known for its emphasis on economic freedom and laissez-faire policies. It is rooted in the belief that individuals should be free to make their own economic decisions without government interference. Austrian economists are known for their focus on the role of entrepreneurship, emphasizing the unique and creative contributions that entrepreneurs make to the economy. They also emphasize the importance of economic processes such as capital accumulation, entrepreneurship, and technological progress in creating economic growth. Austrian economists are critical of central banking and government interventions like stimulus packages and monetary policy, believing that such interventions distort the market and lead to inefficient outcomes. The Austrian School of Economics remains a major force in economics today, with many of its ideas being adopted by governments and businesses around the world. Keynesian Economics is an economic theory that was developed by John Maynard Keynes in the 1930s. The theory states that governments can intervene in the economy to stimulate growth and reduce unemployment. This is done by increasing government spending and reducing taxes. The goal of this theory is to help stabilize the economy by maintaining full employment and keeping prices stable. Keynesian Economics has become a cornerstone of macroeconomic policy and is widely used by governments around the world. It has been a major influence in the development of modern macroeconomic theory and has been the basis for most modern economic policy. It has also been credited with helping to create a more stable and prosperous economy in many countries around the world. Keynesian Economics is an important part of modern economic theory and has had a profound impact on the economies of many countries.
Sources and Further Reading:
Arnsperger, Christian, and Yanis Varoufakis. “What is neoclassical economics.” Post-autistic economics review 38.1 (2006).
Blinder, Alan S. “The fall and rise of Keynesian economics.” Economic record 64.4 (1988): 278- 294.
Boettke, Peter J. The Elgar companion to Austrian economics. Edward Elgar Publishing, 1998.
Campagnolo, Gilles. Criticisms of classical political economy: Menger, Austrian economics and the German historical school. Routledge, 2012.
Dugger, William M. “Methodological differences between institutional and neoclassical economics.” Journal of economic issues 13.4 (1979): 899-909.
Eatwell, John, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman, eds. Marxian economics. Springer, 1990.
Gordon, Robert J. “What is new-Keynesian economics?.” Journal of economic literature 28.3 (1990): 1115-1171.
Henry, John F. The Making of Neoclassical Economics (Routledge Revivals). Routledge, 2012.
Howard, Michael Charles, and John Edward King. “A history of Marxian economics, volume II.” A History of Marxian Economics, Volume II. Princeton University Press, 2014.
Itoh, Makoto. Value and crisis: Essays on Marxian economics in Japan. Monthly Review Press, 2020.
Jahan, Sarwat, Ahmed Saber Mahmud, and Chris Papageorgiou. “What is Keynesian economics.” International Monetary Fund 51.3 (2014): 53-54.
Littlechild, Stephen. Austrian economics. Edward Elgar Publishing, 1990.
Morgan, Jamie. What is Neoclassical Economics?. Taylor & Francis, 2015.
Pearson, Heath. “Was there really a German historical school of economics?.” History of Political Economy 31.3 (1999): 547-562.
Roemer, John E. Analytical foundations of Marxian economic theory. Cambridge University Press, 1981.
Rothbard, Murray N. “Praxeology: The methodology of Austrian economics.” The foundations of modern Austrian economics (1976): 19-39.
Shionoya, Yuichi, ed. The German historical school: the historical and ethical approach to economics. Vol. 40. Routledge, 2000.
Taylor, Thomas C. An introduction to Austrian economics. Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1980.
Tribe, Keith. “Historical schools of economics: German and English.” A companion to the history of economic thought (2003): 215.
Vaughn, Karen I. Austrian economics in America: The migration of a tradition. Cambridge University Press, 1998.